![[personal profile]](https://www.dreamwidth.org/img/silk/identity/user.png)
One of the problems facing the climate-change debate has been the current political shibboleths, and specifically the anti-tax one. Every sensible economist is clear that the *right* way to deal with it is a flat carbon tax: it would address the problem head-on, would probably be least likely to distort markets in unfortunate ways, and would likely be pretty effective. But of course, anything called a "tax" gets peoples' backs up, so we instead wind up with the Democratic leadership creating a classic muddle, in the form of the wildly overcomplex cap-and-trade model. (Which is *probably* better than nothing, but I honestly can't say that with complete confidence.)
So I'm intrigued to read (in last week's Economist) about Maria Cantwell's "cap-and-dividend" proposal. From the description given there (and I need to learn more about the details), it sounds delightfully sensible. Basically, the notion is that any carbon cap will drive up prices: indeed, that's the point of any sensible proposal. So fine: auction off limited permits for all carbon-based fuels, and then bribe everybody with the proceeds. Seriously: take the money from the auctions, and distribute it to the populace. Their back-of-the-napkin kickback calculation is $1000 for a family of four.
It's not perfect, mind -- a carbon-tax system would still be simpler than a cap-based one -- but it's still far simpler than cap-and-trade. If the auction is mandatory and universal, it's likely to succeed in the goal of raising prices and thereby reducing carbon output. And the bribe (which is effectively a progressive redistributive tax, but a very well-disguised one) could be *very* popular if it was marketed properly.
I confess that I'm seesawing between being appalled at the concept, and admiring its elegance. The citizens'-responsibility puritan in me is vaguely unhappy at the notion of bribing the citizens to get them to agree to a system that will help everyone. But the economist in me just loves the way it aligns incentives, and the armchair political quarterback admires the simplicity of the message...
So I'm intrigued to read (in last week's Economist) about Maria Cantwell's "cap-and-dividend" proposal. From the description given there (and I need to learn more about the details), it sounds delightfully sensible. Basically, the notion is that any carbon cap will drive up prices: indeed, that's the point of any sensible proposal. So fine: auction off limited permits for all carbon-based fuels, and then bribe everybody with the proceeds. Seriously: take the money from the auctions, and distribute it to the populace. Their back-of-the-napkin kickback calculation is $1000 for a family of four.
It's not perfect, mind -- a carbon-tax system would still be simpler than a cap-based one -- but it's still far simpler than cap-and-trade. If the auction is mandatory and universal, it's likely to succeed in the goal of raising prices and thereby reducing carbon output. And the bribe (which is effectively a progressive redistributive tax, but a very well-disguised one) could be *very* popular if it was marketed properly.
I confess that I'm seesawing between being appalled at the concept, and admiring its elegance. The citizens'-responsibility puritan in me is vaguely unhappy at the notion of bribing the citizens to get them to agree to a system that will help everyone. But the economist in me just loves the way it aligns incentives, and the armchair political quarterback admires the simplicity of the message...
(no subject)
Date: 2010-02-17 03:57 am (UTC)Yeah. Europe's version doesn't work (http://www.cphpost.dk/news/national/88-national/47643-denmark-rife-with-co2-fraud.html).
[...] but the economics seem basically sound.
Only for the first sale. Once the original owner of the allotment chooses to re-sell his allotment, the cost will still be passed onto the consumer. Since they no longer receive a kickback from the resale, they become a net loser in the process.
This also assumes that companies can't overbuy during the initial sale. I'll bet you dollars to donuts that companies will do everything they can to get spare allocations, as this will give them a cartel position in the new artificial market for pollution.
(Also, it's worth mentioning that your zeroth assumption is not exactly sound. I stopped believing in AGW last year as I dove into Climategate. After following up on the issues that were contained in the e-mails and the software engineer's ReadMe file, I've come to the conclusion that the only data inputs that are actually trustworthy are the satellite data. If you're willing to grind through technical minutia, my journey through the data is haphazardly recorded in this tag (http://meiczyslaw.livejournal.com/tag/climaquiddick).)
(no subject)
Date: 2010-02-17 03:41 pm (UTC)Once the original owner of the allotment chooses to re-sell his allotment, the cost will still be passed onto the consumer. Since they no longer receive a kickback from the resale, they become a net loser in the process.
I'm not seeing it. This proposal is essentially a tax on the basic fuel input. That certainly raises the price all the way down the value chain, but it should have a relatively constant net effect on the end consumer, regardless of how many times it changes hands. Why do you see the end-consumer's cost changing due to allotment resale? Efficient-market theory would seem to argue otherwise, and while I don't actually believe in that theory very far, I do tend to find it a decent rule of thumb.
(Keep in mind that this proposal is *not* cap-and-trade, and has somewhat different dynamics. It'll have problems, but probably not the same ones.)
This also assumes that companies can't overbuy during the initial sale. I'll bet you dollars to donuts that companies will do everything they can to get spare allocations, as this will give them a cartel position in the new artificial market for pollution.
Yep -- that would definitely have to be dealt with. I don't see a good reason to believe it can't be, though -- cartels are an old fact of life, and there are reasonably well-established regulatory approaches for managing them.
I stopped believing in AGW last year as I dove into Climategate.
Not getting into that particular argument, because the reductio ad absurdam comes down to the simple fact that science requires interpretation. I've been following this one pretty closely for a long time, and while I'm willing to grant that there are no certainties about the end result, the *ridiculous* preponderance of evidence points to major climate change happening on a global scale, extremely rapidly by geologic standards. It's essentially a gigantic accidental science experiment being conducted mainly on the basis of wishful thinking, and I have little desire to be in the middle of it.
So seriously: you're going to interpret the data as you like. But by now there is essentially no chance that you're going to convince me that we're not seeing pretty wild change happening, albeit chaotic and hard-to-predict change...
(no subject)
Date: 2010-02-17 04:56 pm (UTC)[...] science requires interpretation.
Indeed. The problem is that, despite the supporters protestations to the contrary, the science is not settled. You have to choose who you're going to trust: Jim Hansen (http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/James_E._Hansen), or Richard Lindzen (http://www-eaps.mit.edu/faculty/lindzen.htm)?
Based on the serious ethical lapses at HadCRUT and IPCC, I can no longer trust their conclusions. That leaves GISS (Hansen) as the only uncorrupted AGW-supporting climate model, and they don't look that good: at the very least, they don't apply their input adjustments consistently; at worst, they might be introducing selection bias through their choice of inputs. It's been very painful going -- having to learn a whole 'nother discipline in order to evaluate its biggest theory is as crunchy as it sounds.
The interesting thing is that my politics haven't changed much -- AGW isn't the linchpin for any of my environmental thinking. The things that are good ideas are still good ideas, because there was always more than one good reason to do them. The bad ideas are still bad ideas, because (like cap-and-trade) they didn't do anything positive in the first place.
Like not drilling for oil in the US: it's not like Americans don't cause oil to be drilled -- we just do it in places like Saudi Arabia, Nigeria, and Venezuela where they don't care about the environment anywhere near as much as we do. Domestic environmental taxes won't end our consumption -- it'll just move the production to someplace with a worse environmental record. How is that a positive thing?
(no subject)
Date: 2010-02-17 06:18 pm (UTC)On the one hand, this is a good argument by classical trade theory. OTOH, the same argument applies to essentially *all* domestic regulations that increase the cost of goods -- which is most of them. World trade manages to stumble along successfully despite that.
That is, you're certainly correct that this would put domestic players at some sort of competitive disadvantage; however, I think you're overstating the end result. It would definitely make things messier, in ways not terribly unlike the way labor regulations do. Like labor regulations, it would become a long-standing bone of contention and argument, would serve as the excuse for periodic trade spats, and most likely would eventually result in some sort of compensatory tariffs if it turned out to make a major difference.
That's not an ideal situation by any means, but I don't see it as especially catastrophic in likely practice. Definitely an argument to make one pause and reflect a bit, and a *fine* argument for trying to craft a system that works at the global level, rather than hacking it at the local one. But waiting for global political change all at once is pretty much the surest recipe to make sure that nothing ever happens; in practice, these things have generally proceeded in fits and starts, beginning in the "first world" and extending slowly outwards from there. I don't see any particular reason to believe this case is likely to be different in the long run.
You have to choose who you're going to trust: Jim Hansen, or Richard Lindzen?
Tsk; strawman argument.
The true answer is that *mostly* I trust The Economist. It's a complex world, and I can't claim to have time to become sufficiently expert on most topics, so like everyone I need to choose my preferred data filter. On a wide variety of topics, I've found The Economist to be calmer, more honest, more balanced and harder to panic than any other source I am aware of. So if we're going to talk about primary influences, that almost certainly counts as my number-one.
On the specific topic of climate change, I've watched over the course of a couple of decades as the magazine has very slowly shifted from being broadly skeptical to broadly certain that *something* is going on here; again, that's based on a broad array of input data from a lot of sources, including the various refutations of the data. I'd summarize their general viewpoint as middle-ground: that the chicken-littles are generally overstating their case, but that it is nonetheless clear that things are broadly warming, and that this is already beginning to have a broad array of side-effects.
I find their presentation consistent with the rest of the information I've found, middle-ground and pragmatic as I generally expect from them, and generally convincing.
Domestic environmental taxes won't end our consumption -- it'll just move the production to someplace with a worse environmental record. How is that a positive thing?
Again, strawman. Nobody's talking about ending consumption. The point here is *reducing* fossil-fuel-based energy consumption, and I suspect the proposal at hand would be moderately successful at that. Yes, there would be side-effects that have to be mitigated (no plan ever survives contact with reality), and no, it's not a panacea. But it's extremely unlikely that *all* of that energy usage would be shifted offshore; indeed, I find it pretty unlikely that more than a modest minority would be, after all the social and political feedback loops play out. So again, I think you're overstating...
(no subject)
Date: 2010-02-18 06:38 am (UTC)Which is a long way to go to say, "James Hansen."
But why do you trust The Economist? What makes you think that they're the most reliable intermediary? What makes their writers less susceptible to the forces that befuddle the most well-intentioned journalists covering scientific issues?
To me, the anonymity of their writers is one The Economist's weaknesses. Because of this cloak, there's no way to evaluate their qualifications, biases, and histories. In contrast, I know that Ben Goldacre (of The Guardian) doesn't actually care to understand climate change (as he's said in not so many words), so he's not really a reliable intermediary on that subject. I also know his politics (and his religion!), so I know which articles of his to verify. But this also means that I know which issues I can trust him as an authority, because I know about his faults (and his background as a medical doctor).
Slightly off topic: In between his snark, Goldacre's site Bad Science (http://www.badscience.net/) is a good source for understanding the pressures that a science journalist faces. That education is one of the reasons I've started looking at the primary sources more, as it's excessively easy for a journalist to make an innocent mistake that changes the meaning of an article.